LABOUR MOBILITY
Labor mobility refers to the ease with which laborers are able to move around within an economy and between different economies. Geographic mobility refers to a worker's ability to work in a particular physical location, while occupational mobility refers to a worker's ability to change job types.
What is Mobility of Labor? The movement of Laborers or workers, from place to place, profession to profession, and from one grade to another grade, is known as mobility of labor. The movement of laborers or workers from one place to another by the prospects of better wages is called geographical or place mobility.
The movement between trade and trade of an almost equally paying nature is called horizontal or professional mobility.
Capacity for horizontal mobility can be very much developed at the early stages of the training of labor. This kind of mobility helps laborers a great deal when they are thrown out of work from any particular industry. They can exercise options and can join any profession from among several ones that they have learned.
There is another kind of mobility is called vertical mobility. When a man of talents and qualifications gets into the higher grade and gets work according to his superior capacity and talents, his output of work is greater than formerly, and the society as a whole stands to gain thereby.
Importance of the Mobility of Labor: Mobility is one of those factors that go to promote the efficiency of labor in a country. Labor should have the capacity of readily adjust or shift itself in accordance with the requirements of each case. Labor gains in personal prospects by mobility.
In a country like India, where the economic transition is going on, there is great friction, and the forces of competition are not fully at work, mobility of labor brings about equalization of wages as between place and place, and class and class. Besides the gain in adaptability that the moving laborer acquires, there is a gain in utility under conditions of full competition.
Labour mobility consists of changes in the location of workers both across physical space
(geographic mobility) and across a set of jobs (occupational mobility). Geographic mobility can
be further subdivided into short-distance and long-distance moves, as well as into voluntary and
coerced migration. Occupational mobility can be lateral (within a broad class of jobs similar in
socioeconomic status) or vertical (from one job to a better or worse job).
The availability of
large, nationally-representative longitudinal surveys in the late twentieth century has made it
possible to measure the extent of mobility in all these dimensions, and how they are related, in
several developed economies. Our understanding of the extent of labor mobility through history
has been enhanced by work conducted since the 1970s in which the careers of individual
workers are reconstructed by locating them in censuses and census-like enumerations (city
directories, tax lists, population registers) at successive dates.
At the aggregate level, labor mobility conveys important economic benefits. The reallocation of
workers across regions permits the exploitation of complementary resources as they are
discovered in new places, while reallocation across sectors makes possible the use of new
technologies and the growth of new industries. At the individual level, mobility allows for
improvements in the economic circumstances of those whose skills or aspirations are a poor
match for the job or location in which they find themselves.
The impact of labor mobility extends well beyond these economic considerations, however.
The ability of fluid U.S. labor markets to deter labor radicalization has been recognized by
Karl Marx, Selig Perlman, and Stephan Thernstrom. Since the work of Frederick Jackson Turner
more than a century ago, scholars have debated the role of the frontier in forging a particularly
American political economy in the U.S. Sociologists have examined the impact of mobility on
the operation of communities and interpersonal relationships, and political scientists have
considered how mobility affects political participation and coalition formation.
Types of Mobility of Labour:
- Geographical Mobility
- Occupational Mobility
- (a) Horizontal Mobility
- (b) Vertical Mobility
- Mobility between Industries
- Education and Training
- Outlook or Urge
- Social Set-up
Measurement of labor mobility requires examination of sources that either record an individual's location or occupation at two or more points in time or allow inferences to be drawn regarding how the locations or occupations of a particular group of individuals have changed over time.
The mobility of labor depends on the extent to which labor is educated and trained. The more a person is educated and skilled, the greater his chances of moving from one occupation or place to another. Geographical and vertical mobility depends on education and training.
Factor mobility refers to the ability to move factors of production—labor, capital, or land—out of one production process into another. Factor mobility may involve the movement of factors between firms within an industry, such as when one steel plant closes but sells its production equipment to another steel firm.
LABOUR MOBILITY IN EUROPE
Information on the occupational mobility of labor in Europe is rare before the nineteenth
century. Parish records and civilian population registers, however, provide a glimpse of labor’s
geographic mobility. High rates of geographic mobility can be seen well before the advent of
modern industrial economies. Young workers in agriculture were employed off the family farm
as farm servants in Britain throughout the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, moving to
different farms at the end of each year. On the Continent, gangs of workers followed the harvest
across national borders, returning to their home villages after months at a time on the road.
Though much of this movement was only temporary, a more permanent move to villages and
towns was essential to the growth of the cottage industry. Several transnational migrations (the Irish
into Britain, the Belgians into France, Poles into Germany) were prominent features of European
industrial and urban growth.
Recent research on labor mobility in Britain has produced more detailed conclusions. The
British populace of the nineteenth century was highly mobile. England, Wales, and Scotland
were virtually free of institutional barriers to geographic mobility.
Though the Poor Law’s
provision of a degree of economic security created some disincentive to mobility, it was small
compared to the effects of large-scale social welfare programs of the twentieth century.
Nineteenth-century Britain saw both high rates of internal mobility and overseas emigration.
Emigrants left primarily for the United States, though many also went to Canada and Australia.
These long-distance movers tended to be young, single, and male. Internal migration within
England, Wales, and Scotland was a very different phenomenon. Between 1851 and 1881,
approximately one in four people changed their county of residence; more than half moved from
one town to another. Like overseas migrants, internal movers tended to be young.
Unlike
overseas migrants, more females moved within the country than did males, and single people
were no more likely to move than were married people.
Most strikingly, internal moves tended to cover very short distances. Between 1851 and 1881,
the average internal migrant moved only 35 miles; one quarter moved less than five miles. There
was no clear regional pattern to nineteenth-century internal migration, unlike the steady flow of
westward migrants in the U.S. at the time. One of the most distinctive patterns of British internal
migration was the prevalence of rural-to-urban moves. Virtually all of Britain’s nineteenth-century population growth was accruing to the cities, which expanded both by natural increase
and by population influx from the rural areas.
In the mid-1800s, more than one out of every three
rural residents of Great Britain left for an urban area. Most left for the nearest city, though
London drew migrants from all over the country, as it had since the seventeenth century. The
industrialized urban areas of Lancashire and Yorkshire also drew many rural migrants.
Overseas emigrants and internal migrants within Britain moved for many reasons, but chief
among them was the search for economic gain. Wage gaps and the chance for upward
occupational mobility drew migrants to the U.S. and to the cities.
The British labor market did
not exhibit as much occupational mobility, either between or within generations, as it did
geographically. Nineteenth-century marriage registries indicate that well over half of all sons worked
in jobs of similar socioeconomic status to their fathers. Following males across censuses reveals
a similar pattern over the individual career history: more than half of all males did not change
socioeconomic status over their careers. The socioeconomic status and occupation of the father
exerted a strong influence on the socioeconomic status of the son; however, the opportunity did exist
to improve the odds of mobility.
The cities provided one such opportunity. Males who moved
from a rural to an urban area experienced more upward mobility than they would have had they
remained. Education provided another avenue of mobility. Sons from all economic backgrounds
were more likely to exceed their father’s socioeconomic status if they attended some elementary
school than if they did not, and the likelihood increased with years of schooling.
LABOUR MOBILITY IN THE U.S.
The most important form of labour mobility in the first century of European settlement of North
America was voluntary immigration from Europe by whites and coerced immigration from
Africa by blacks. In the absence of immigration, many of the initial settlements would not have
survived, given the high mortality rates and low rates of natural increase. Three-quarters of the
white arrivals may have been indentured servants who agreed to work for a period of four to
seven years to repay their passage fare. By the 1680s, black slaves were being imported as well
to work in Southern tobacco and rice cultivation.
Since the start of the seventeenth century, Americans have experienced high rates of labor
mobility within the colonies and later within the U.S., This stems from the propensity of those
who have migrated once (like trans-Atlantic immigrants) to make subsequent moves. Even
among the native-born, though, mobility was frequent, because of both the availability of largely
unsettled land through the end of the nineteenth century and an absence of restrictions on
movement across locations or across jobs. Though colonial governments attempted to reduce
mobility by requiring permission for travel and imposing severe penalties on runaway workers,
there is little reason to believe these measures were successful. The absence of strong craft guilds
and the absence of organized labor generally down through the 1880s made occupational
mobility similarly free from restrictions.
Before 1900, American workers were employed largely
through “spot” markets in which job attachment was weak and turnover rates were high. By the
1920s, as more formal systems of recruitment and labor monitoring evolved, job tenure
increased, though it remained substantially below levels observed in other developed counties
throughout the twentieth century.
Measurement of labor mobility requires examination of sources that either record an
individual’s location or occupation at two or more points in time or allow inferences to be drawn
regarding how the locations or occupations of a particular group of individuals have changed
over time.
For the colonial period, only a few generalizations are possible. Indentured servants in
the South had good success in improving their socioeconomic status after their term of service
ended through the 1660s, but were apparently less successful later. As land prices rose in the late
seventeenth-century tobacco boom, more found it necessary to migrate to another colony to find
success. Colonial army muster rolls show high rates of geographic mobility by the Revolutionary
War.
In the middle of the nineteenth century, it is possible to measure labor mobility directly by
following individuals from one census to another. Between 1850 and 1860, roughly two-thirds of
adult males moved from one county to another, with higher migration rates among less skilled
workers.
Migrants experienced more occupational mobility (both upward and downward) than
otherwise similar non-migrants. The work of Frederick Jackson Turner and a generation of
historians examined the importance of the frontier as a place where workers could improve their
circumstances. More recent research validates this view of the frontier: workers who went there
indeed did better than they would have done at their places of origin. Beginning in the 1840s,
workers also migrated in large numbers from farms to cities. Many of these were young women
and children employed in New England textile mills and the younger sons of farm households
whose prospects were unfavorable in the farm sector.
The available evidence on wages in the first half of the nineteenth century demonstrates that the
movement of workers to the west was successful in eliminating inter-regional wage differences
within both the northern and southern tiers of states (though pronounced north-south differentials
remained).
The movement of workers from farms to cities and towns eliminated any substantial wage
gap between farm and urban workers, after adjusting for cost-of-living differences.
Among those who remained in agriculture, both geographic and occupational mobility can be
seen throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Farmers migrated in large numbers
from the Middle Atlantic and South Atlantic states to regions farther west, generally moving
along lines of latitude both to economize on the direct cost of migration and to take better
advantage of latitude-specific farming skills.
As farm-making costs and the prices of existing
farms increased, some individuals found it increasingly difficult to purchase farms early in their
careers. By 1900, as many as a quarter of the nation’s farms were occupied by tenants, with
higher tenancy rates in the South. Though concern increased in the 1920s and 1930s that
mobility from tenant to owner was becoming increasingly difficult, particularly in the South,
recent evidence finds that tenancy remained merely a stage in the eventual transition to
ownership.
Throughout the second half of the nineteenth century and into the 1920s, voluntary immigration
from Europe provided millions of new workers for the economy. Most were able to enter better
jobs after their entry than they possessed in Europe.
Beginning in the 1910s, an additional form
of labor mobility can be seen: large numbers of black farm workers (the descendants of slaves
forcibly transported to the South from Africa) migrated voluntarily to Northern cities where they
took up urban employment.
Few sources make possible long-run comparisons of labor mobility in different eras. In the
1850s, migration across county boundaries was more common than it was in the 1970s. Upward
occupational mobility was also somewhat more common in the 1850s than in 1970, both in
comparisons of fathers’ and sons’ occupations and in comparisons of individuals’ first and last
occupations.
COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVES ON LABOUR MOBILITY
A recent research project that follows the careers of thousands of young men from the early
1850s to the early 1880s in both the U.S. and the U.K. makes it possible to compare the extent of
labor mobility in these two developing economies. Both de Tocqueville and Marx claimed that
mobility was far more common in the U.S. than in the U.K. This study supports their assertions:
in both geography and occupation, U.S. workers were twice as mobile as U.K. workers. Sons
improved upon the occupational status of their fathers more often in the U.S., and occupational
ascent between first and last jobs was also more frequent in the U.S.